Quote of the day

“I find economics increasingly satisfactory, and I think I am rather good at it.”– John Maynard Keynes

Sunday, 29 April 2018

Must-read on middle income trap

If I'd read this before your mock, put it here and you had read it & digested, it could have added 4-5 marks to your Paper 3 essay(s). I have highlighted one absolutely critical paragraph (even my son realised this was crucial), and put a line at the bottom of the part that is important - below the ******* it becomes an analysis of statsistical application, which is not so important:

Mixed-income myths - The Economist October 7th 2017

The middle-income trap has little evidence going for it
Countries that are neither rich nor poor can hold their own against rivals at both extremes

EVERY FEW YEARS Foreign Affairs, a magazine about international relations, provokes a fracas in a neighbouring discipline, international economics. In 1994 it published an essay by Paul Krugman, “The Myth of Asia’s Miracle”, which re-examined the source of the tigers’ success. Then, after the Asian financial crisis, it came up with “The Capital Myth” by Jagdish Bhagwati, which re-examined the case for free capital flows, the source of the tigers’ humiliation. In 2004 it offered “Globalisation’s Missing Middle” by Geoffrey Garrett, then at the University of California, Los Angeles. This essay is cited much less often than the other two, but in a roundabout way it has been equally influential. It argued that middle-ranked countries were in a bind, unable to compete either with the cutting-edge technology of rich nations or the cut-throat prices of poor ones. “Middle-income countries”, it said, “have not done nearly as well under globalised markets as either richer or poorer countries.”

To prove his point, Mr Garrett ranked the world’s economies by GDP per person in 1980, dividing them into three groups: top, middle and bottom. He then compared their growth by that measure over the subsequent two decades, finding that the middle-ranked economies grew more slowly than either the top or bottom ones. Three years later Homi Kharas and Indermit Gill of the World Bank cited Mr Garrett’s essay in a book about East Asia’s growth prospects. They invented the term “middle-income trap”, which subsequently took on a life of its own.

The trap can be interpreted in a variety of ways, which may be one reason why so many people believe in it. Some confuse the trap with the simple logic of catch-up growth. According to that logic, poorer countries can grow faster than richer ones because imitation is easier than innovation and because capital earns higher returns when it is scarce. By the same logic, a country’s growth will naturally slow down as the gap with the leading economies narrows and the scope for catch-up growth diminishes. All else equal, then, middle-income countries should grow more slowly than poorer ones. But Mr Garrett was making a bolder argument: that middle-income countries tend to grow more slowly than both poorer and richer economies. 

The notion of a trap resonated widely with policymakers, note Messrs Kharas and Gill, especially in countries where growth had lost its lustre. Najib Razak, Malaysia’s prime minister, began talking about it in 2009. Trap-talk also spread to Vietnam’s leaders in 2009 and appeared in South Africa’s National Development Plan in 2012.



By far the most prominent trap-watcher is China, one of the few middle-income economies that is more than middle-sized. In 2015 Lou Jiwei, then China’s finance minister, said that his country had a 50% chance of falling into the trap in the next five to ten years. The same fear haunts Liu He, an influential economic adviser to Xi Jinping, China’s president. Mr Liu was one of the driving forces behind a report entitled “China 2030”, published in 2012 by his Development Research Centre (DRC) and the World Bank. The report featured a chart that has perhaps done more than any other to spread the idea of a middle-income trap (see chart). It showed that of 101 countries which counted as middle-income in 1960, only 13 had achieved high-income status by 2008. The rest spent the intervening 50 years trapped in mediocrity or worse.

Slow and queasy

The evidence in the chart and Mr Garrett’s essay was suggestive but hardly systematic. However, it was buttressed by a more rigorous pair of studies by Barry Eichengreen of the University of California, Berkeley, Donghyun Park of the Asian Development Bank and Kwanho Shin of Korea University, which reached similar conclusions. They looked for fast-growing economies that subsequently suffered sustained slowdowns (defining fast growth as at least 3.5% per person, and a slowdown as a two-percentage-point drop in growth, both averaged over seven years). Their research indicated that these slowdowns seemed to cluster at GDP levels of $11,000 and $15,000 per person (converted into dollars at purchasing-power parity). 

Perhaps the most sophisticated analysis was published by Shekhar Aiyar and his colleagues at the IMF in 2013. They sought to distinguish between growth traps and the natural slowdown that any country can expect as it converges with leading economies. To do this, they first calculated an expected growth path for each country, based on its income per person as well as its human and physical capital. Second, they looked for countries that were growing faster or slower than expected, resulting in positive or negative growth gaps. Third, they looked for unusually severe and sustained slowdowns, when these growth gaps widened sharply. They found that middle-income countries were more likely to suffer such setbacks, no matter how middle income was defined.

The combined weight of this economic evidence and policymakers’ intuition is hard to ignore, and seems to justify scepticism about the growth prospects of China, Malaysia, Thailand and many other emerging economies. But neither the intuition nor the number-crunching is as convincing as it looks.

Intuitively, it seems to make sense that middle-income countries will be squeezed between higher-tech and lower-wage rivals on either side. But those rivals rely on high technology or low wages for a reason. Rich economies need advanced technologies and skills to offset high wages. Poor countries, for their part, need low wages to offset low levels of technology and skill. The obvious conclusion is that middle-income countries can and do compete with both, combining middling wages with middling levels of skill, technology and productivity.

To be sure, those average levels mask huge variations. Most economies have a mix of impressive leading firms and unsophisticated stragglers. The productivity of the top quarter of American firms is at least 4.86 times that of the bottom quarter, according to a study by Eric Bartelsman, Jonathan Haskel and Ralf Martin published by the Centre for Economic Policy Research. In developing countries the gaps are even bigger. Indeed, middle-income countries are often more accurately described as mixed-income economies.



Shaping the mix are at least four possible sources of growth in GDP per person. The first is moving workers from overmanned fields to more productive factories (structural transformation). The second is adding more capital such as machinery per worker (capital-deepening). The third is augmenting capital or labour by making it more sophisticated, perhaps by adopting techniques that a firm, industry or country has not previously embraced (technological diffusion). The final source of growth derives from advances in technology that introduce something new to the world at large (technological innovation).

Economists find it helpful to keep these sources of growth separate in their minds. The mistake is to think they remain separate between countries. In reality, in most countries several of these forces are at work simultaneously, at different paces and in varying proportions. Countries do not wait until the last surplus farm worker has left the fields to begin capital-deepening. Nor do they wait until the returns to brute capital accumulation have been exhausted before they start to increase the sophistication of their production techniques. So development does not proceed in discrete stages that require a nationwide leap from one stage to the next. It is more like a long-distance race, with a leading pack and many stragglers, in which the result is an average of everyone’s finishing times. The more stragglers in the race, the more room for improvement.

Positive splits

The statistical work by Messrs Eichengreen, Park and Shin shows that middle-income countries do suffer slowdowns. But since it looks only at countries with an income per person of over $10,000, it cannot say whether they are more vulnerable to such setbacks than poor countries. That was not a question the authors ever intended to answer. When their method is extended to countries further down the income scale, it turns out that slowdowns among poorer economies are at least as prevalent as among middle-income ones.

Countries in the middle do slow more often than rich countries, but that is partly because rich economies rarely grow fast enough (3.5% per person over seven years) to be eligible for a slowdown as the paper defines it. Nor is such a slowdown sufficient to trap an economy. Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan have all endured at least one, and none of them is trapped in middle income. Growth in China’s GDP per person has also slowed, to about 7.6% over the past seven years, against more than 10% over the previous seven. That qualifies as a sharp slowdown by the authors’ definition. But China is not trapped; it is still growing faster than most countries, rich or poor.

A similar problem bedevils the paper by Mr Aiyar and his IMF colleagues. To see why, suppose a miracle economy were to grow much faster than an economist would expect, given its level of income, schooling and capital. Imagine its growth were then to moderate to a more normal pace. That might count as a severe slowdown by the authors’ definition (since the country’s highly positive growth gap has dropped to zero), even though the economy was still converging on high income at a normal pace.

Or suppose a country were rapidly to increase its investment in schooling and physical capital to avoid the middle-income trap. If the strategy were successful, it might result in steady growth. But with the method used by the IMF paper, that constant growth could nonetheless count as a severe slowdown because, other things being equal, their model expects improved education and deeper capital to raise the pace of growth, not merely shore it up.

***************************************************************************************************

Neither of these papers, then, proves the existence of a middle-income trap as commonly understood. Indeed, Mr Eichengreen has said that his line of research was intended to explore different questions. But what about the DRC’s and World Bank’s “killer” China 2030 chart?

Its criteria for middle income are idiosyncratic. They include any country with a GDP per person between 5.2% and 42.75% of America’s, measured at purchasing-power parity. The good news is that eight countries on the chart (including Turkey, Malaysia, Oman and Poland) have since escaped the middle-income bracket thanks to better data or further growth. Ten others, the Slovak Republic among them, have also crossed that threshold but were not included on the chart because either the data or the countries themselves did not exist in 1960.

But the chart contains a more fundamental flaw. Its criteria for middle-income are too broad to be useful. By its definition, a country with a GDP of just $590 per person (at 1990 prices) counted as middle income in 1960. That includes countries like China in the middle of its Great Famine. At the other extreme, a country with a GDP per person of $13,300 in 2008 also counted as middle income. This upper threshold for 2008 is more than 2,000% higher than the lower one for 1960. No wonder so many countries remained stuck in between them.

One of them was China. Its GDP per person increased tenfold between 1960 and 2008, despite the famine and the Cultural Revolution. But because it started that period above $590 and ended it below $13,300, it remained confined to the middle square of the China 2030 grid.

One of the World Bank staff involved in the China 2030 report has subsequently co-written a paper investigating the middle-income trap more closely. It found no “evidence for [unusual] stagnation at any particular middle-income level”. More recently, research by Xuehui Han of the Asian Development Bank and Shang-Jin Wei of Columbia, and separately by Lant Pritchett and Larry Summers of Harvard, has also cast doubt on the trap. Another Harvard economist, Robert Barro, the doyen of empirical growth studies, thinks that “this idea is a myth.” The transition from middle to upper income is certainly “challenging”, he writes. But it is no more challenging than the transition from low to middle.

Messrs Kharas and Gill are themselves agnostic about the precise definition and empirical salience of the term they invented. They introduced it “with modesty, because we had not rigorously established its prevalence”, they wrote ten years later. Since some middle-income countries have undeniably stagnated, barriers to their growth clearly exist. As Messrs Kharas and Gill see it, what matters is whether these threats take a distinctive “middle-income” form, not whether they are more common or severe than the dangers facing other economies.

Trappist agnosticism

The duo came up with the term chiefly because the economics profession seemed to offer no clear or convincing growth recipe for middle-income countries. Partly as a result, policymakers often felt caught between two stools: either they clung on to old growth strategies (such as low-end manufacturing) for too long, or they embraced sophisticated models (such as the “knowledge economy”) too soon. The middle-income trap is really a middle-income dilemma.

What about Mr Garrett’s original finding in Foreign Affairs, which helped inform the thinking of Messrs Kharas and Gill? An effort to replicate that exercise, with newer data covering the same 20 years, shows a much narrower gap between middle- and high-income growth for the period from 1980 to 2000. And that gap all but disappears if the countries are divided into three groups of equal size, rather than Mr Garrett’s somewhat arbitrary 25-45-30% split.

More importantly, middle-income countries, even by his definition, grew faster than their high-income counterparts over the two decades from 1990 to 2010, as well as from 1995 to 2015. It seems that in the 1990s and 2000s middle-income countries were quite capable of competing with cutting-edge economies. So what tripped them up in the 1980s? Part of the answer may lie with America’s Federal Reserve.

Tuesday, 17 April 2018

Solution to housing crisis? Great Micro info.

The Californians have a problem very similar to ours - rising population and severe restrictions on building, pushing up house prices to extremes. However, there is a proposed solution, and much of this could come into a housing essay. I am putting the article here, but there is also a Q&A with the bill proposer, which chucks in some tricky questions - here is the link.

The future of housing policy is being decided in California

A chat with the activist who first dreamed up SB 827, a sweeping new bill that addresses California’s housing crisis.

Shutterstock
California is in the midst of crippling housing crisis. The state’s population has steadily grown, but it hasn’t been building new places for people to live at anything close to the same rate. It now ranks 49th in housing units per capita.
The predictable consequence of demand growing faster than supply is that existing housing in the state, especially in its biggest cities, has become insanely expensive. Seven of the 10 most expensive US real estate markets are Californian. The median home price in the state is $524,000; in San Francisco it is approaching $1.3 million.
Rising prices push middle-class workers further and further from their jobs, leading to unhealthy commutes and traffic congestion. Low-income Californians are increasingly forced to choose between rent and food or health care, adding to the state’s hunger and health problems, or being pushed out of housing altogether, adding to its burgeoning homeless population. According to analysts at McKinsey, the housing crisis is costing California $140 billion a year in lost economic output.

State lawmakers are finally beginning to take the crisis seriously. Last year, Gov. Jerry Brown and the California legislature passed a slate of 15 housing bills, which would (among other things) raise almost $1 billion a year to subsidize affordable housing. More housing bills are slated for 2018. Meanwhile, the state transportation agency, CalTrans, is aiming to double transit ridership between 2015 and 2020, in part to encourage urban density.

A tangle of land-use restrictions makes it difficult to build homes in California

But those legislative reforms are fighting against an artificially constrained market. The basic problem remains: It is difficult to build housing in California, thanks in part to a thicket of local parking regulations, building requirements, zoning restrictions, and bureaucratic choke points. The state’s (generally whiter, wealthier) residents use these tools to prevent new construction that might house (generally more diverse, poorer) newcomers.
As long as supply is artificially constrained and demand continues growing, affordable housing subsidies will never be able to keep up. As long as localities can’t or won’t build dense housing near train stations and bus stops, transit investments won’t pay off like they could.
A graph from an excellent CalMatters explainer on the CA housing crisis.
A graph from an excellent CalMatters explainer on the CA housing crisis.
CalMatters
Now, there is a solution on the table that goes directly after this root cause. SB 827, a new bill before the California Senate, would require that all areas within a half-mile of a high-frequency transit stop, or within a quarter-mile of a bus or transit corridor, allow heights of at least 45 or 85 feet (depending on distance from transit, width of street, and other characteristics). That’s roughly four to eight stories, far higher than what many local zoning commissions allow.

SB 827 would also waive any minimum parking requirements in those areas and prohibit any design requirement that would have the effect of arbitrarily lowering the square footage allowed on a lot.
The bill’s changes would apply to huge swathes of the state, including the majority of land in several major cities. It would unleash dense development In markets long dominated by powerful anti-housing activists (often called NIMBYs, for Not In My Backyard). It represents a housing revolution.

The bill was recently introduced by state Sen. Scott Wiener, along with co-authors Assembly member Phil Ting and Sen. Nancy Skinner. Unsurprisingly, it has drawn heated opposition from the aforementioned NIMBYs. 

What remains to be seen is how the state’s powerful low-income and social-justice community will come down on it. Recently, a coalition of such groups sent Wiener a letter opposing the bill, based on fears that development will displace low-income residents near transit, increasing housing stock but exacerbating inequality. At present, the bill contains no explicit measures to prevent such displacement. (Its sponsors say they are working on adding some.)

The housing advocate behind SB 827 is spoiling for a fight

To answer that and other questions about the bill, I called the guy who dreamed it up, Brian Hanlon. A longtime housing advocate, Hanlon helped start the California Renters Legal Advocacy and Education Fund, which provides legal advice to renters.

Last year, after some success helping write, push, and ultimately pass SB 167 (which strengthened California’s Housing Accountability Act), Hanlon started a new group of pro-housing advocates called California YIMBY (Yes In My Back Yard). Its mission is to back a suite of housing bills including SB 827, which he helped develop and sell to lawmakers.

Despite the sweeping effects of the bill, Hanlon says the reaction has been largely positive. Among other things, SB 827 is exposing a deep split in the state’s environmental community between those focused on climate change and urban density (generally younger) and those focused on old-school preservation and population limits (generally older). “These tensions have been simmering for a while,” Hanlon says, “but I think this is the bill that’s going to force people to pick a side.”
The bill will go through several committees in the California Senate and Assembly, likely picking up changes and amendments along the way. Its final fate will be clear by September or October.
My conversation with Hanlon has been edited for length and clarity.
california sprawl
Not very dense.
Shutterstock

Sunday, 15 April 2018

Great FT video on rail nationalisation

Hat tip to Mr Hagan for spotting this. Chock full of good material for nationalisation questions from both sides of the argument:


Sunday, 8 April 2018

Micro - Gender Pay Gap

If gender pay gap is part of your A2 micro syllabus, this  piece from the IEA looks a good place to get some evaluative information - I've tested the first link, but if it doesn't work try going here :

A-gender bender

This week marked the deadline for large companies to reveal their gender pay gap statistics, as mandated in new government legislation.



Many are branding the measures - which require all companies with 250+ employees to report a variety of pay gap data - as “groundbreaking”. Yet in reality, the data has added little to the debate, and is likely to take us further away from the truth.  

Kate Andrews, News Editor at the IEA, released a new briefing to coincide with the deadline, which highlighted how the new requirements create a misleading picture of gender pay and female achievements in the workplace.


Crucially, the measures fail to factor in key differentials, like job, background, education level, age, years of experience and distinction between
full-time and part-time work. Without access to these kinds of data, the reporting tells us very little about men and women doing comparable work and is rendered meaningless, she argued.


There is also a danger that the measures could create worse outcomes for women - by, for example, disincentivising companies from hiring young women at the start of their careers, in the hope of massaging their pay gap figures.
Download the briefing for free here.
The report was covered by Al Jazeera and City AM, as well as by BBC Radio 4’s Today programme, where Kate took part in an interview, which you can listen to here.


She also wrote for the i newspaper, highlighting the flaws of the pay gap reporting measures, and for the Times Thunderer, arguing that now is the time to reclaim feminism from the radicals, who intentionally try to downplay the success of working women.
Following on from the report, Kate appeared across the media this week, dispelling some of the more egregious claims made about gender pay.


She took part in a heated debate with the Labour MP Stella Creasy on Sky News, which was written up in the Spectator’s Steerpike column and on the Guido Fawkes website.

Kate also appeared on: BBC Newsnight, Channel 4 News, BBC News, BBC World, the Victoria Derbyshire Show, Sky News bulletins, Channel 5’s The Wright Stuff, talkRADIO, Scotland Tonight, the Spectator's Coffee House Shots podcast, BBC Radio Scotland and a host of local radio stations.




Meanwhile, Julian Jessop, the IEA’s Chief Economist, also spent some time debunking the new reporting measures.
He appeared on BBC Radio 4’s Today programme as well, and was quoted in The Guardian on why examining the percentage of men and women in each quartile of the business could be a more useful exercise than comparing hourly gender pay gaps.
Julian also wrote a blog for the IEA website, explaining the major problems with the crude data being released, which you can read here.

Spoiling Mr Bool's breakfast:

and possibly being a tad too pessimistic, but the reasons in here are solid - lift yourselves above the pack by having this as evaluation material:

The eurozone is already heading back into recession – and that could be catastrophic

Retail sales are falling sharply. Industrial production is slumping. Construction is sluggish and the government is weak and clueless with little idea of how to respond to falling demand. No, don’t worry, you haven’t accidentally stumbled across a hardcore remoaner rant about a declining, irrelevant Britain. That is actually a description of what is meant to be the eurozone’s strongest economy – Germany. 
Very few people seem to have noticed it yet but there are worrying signs the exporting powerhouse at the centre of the eurozone is slowing down sharply. True, it might only be a blip. Then again, that is how most recessions start. If that is what is happening, and the evidence is mounting all the time, then it will be catastrophic for the whole single currency area. No progress has been made on reform, policy responses are limited and electorates are exhausted by austerity. One more downturn might be the last. 
Most mainstream economists have bought into the story that the eurozone is booming this year. Led by a powerful Germany, with France reviving under president Macron, and with a central bank that is still pumping the economy with printed money and near-zero interest rates, production has been rising and joblessness finally falling. Heck, even Italy and Greece have been growing again. Investors have been pouring cash into the continent, and the currency has been soaring, as anyone planning a holiday in France or Spain will quickly discover. 
But hold on. There are some suspicious numbers emerging that don’t quite fit that narrative. Start with Germany. This week we learnt retail sales dropped by 0.7pc in February. They have fallen in six of the last eight months and all of the last three. On Friday, industrial production figures showed output down by 1.6pc, the largest monthly fall in three years. Factory orders came in way below expectations this week, with a mere 0.3pc rebound after the 3.5pc drop in January, and construction spending is also down. In fact, the only part of the German economy still expanding is its export industry, but even that is under threat. 
At the same time, Angela Merkel’s patched-together Grand Coalition seems unlikely to respond with any form of stimulus, while Germany will be the biggest loser from Donald Trump’s trade wars. 
True, employment growth is still OK (although rather like this country, nearly all the new jobs go to lowly paid immigrants). But that is not a leading indicator like retail sales and factory output. “We are not calling for a recession in Germany … yet”, argued High Frequency Economics in a note this week. “We are suggesting that the peak of economic growth for this cycle has been realised.” Once you are passed a peak, of course, then the only way is down. 
Across the eurozone as a whole, the outlook is not looking much better. Retail sales for the whole region rose a mere 0.1pc in February compared to the 0.5pc forecast. France is especially weak, with retail stagnant, and a nasty 1.9pc fall in household real income for January and for the year as a whole. A long summer of strikes is not going to help that economy, especially as its huge tourist industry needs the trains and planes running again to prosper.  
Over in Italy, there is at least some growth, which is a miracle given its experience of the single currency, but the jobs numbers came in below expectations this month. None of those figures fit the picture of an economy that is booming. In fact they look increasingly like one that is heading into a German-led downturn. 
In truth, the growth of the last two years has been mostly an illusion. The European Central Bank has chucked 2.2 trillion of freshly printed euros at the economy and slashed interest rates as close to zero as it can possibly get. It would be extraordinary if that amount of cash didn’t stimulate some kind of revival. But the key question was always this: would quantitative easing kick-start a genuine recovery, as it has in the United States, or to a more limited extent in the UK? Or would it, as it has in Japan for 20 years, merely generate a feeble revival that almost immediately runs out of steam? 
Right now, it is starting to look as if we have the answer. The eurozone is another Japan. After all, without a strong Germany, the region can’t grow. It accounts for 23pc of the zone’s GDP and has created 38pc of the new jobs in Europe over the last five years. And Germany has stopped expanding. 
The last recession led to a dramatic crisis within the eurozone. Greece, Ireland and Portugal had to be bailed out, and Spain and Italy came within a whisker of the same fate. The next one will be far harder. 
There have been no meaningful reforms to make the single currency work better. Indeed, in the background, the imbalances have grown even worse, with Germany’s shocking trade surplus draining demand from the rest of the continent. The ECB is out of policy responses. The banking system looks in worse shape than ever (suspiciously, Deutsche Bank’s shares keep hitting fresh lows – almost as if something was up in its home market). In the peripheral countries, voters are exhausted by austerity and low growth. In the core, Angela Merkel now looks too weak to impose a solution should a fresh crisis erupt. 
In truth, a fresh recession may well be terminal. Of course, it may not happen. The latest data may just be a few rogue figures, followed by a swift recovery as most mainstream forecasters still predict. Even so, the warning signs are clear enough. The markets are ignoring them right now. But that doesn’t mean they aren’t real – and if they are the eurozone is heading for big trouble.

Useful article about tax changes

A bit more sophisticated than just using the LAffer Curve:

Regional taxes are a breath of fresh air

If you are Scottish, there was some bad news this week. It wasn’t just the weather or another droning policy speech from Nicola Sturgeon. It was this. Your taxes just went up. From the start of this tax year, Scotland imposed a new higher rate of 46pc on its highest-earning citizens. For the first time, the amount of your monthly pay packet taken by government will vary across the different countries of the United Kingdom.
It is not just Scotland, however. If you are Welsh, and buying and selling a property, you will also face a new form of property tax. Likewise, in Northern Ireland you may soon have a different rate of corporation tax.
Piece by piece, tax competition is arriving between the countries of the UK. You can debate the pros and cons of each individual tweak for as long as you want. But one point is surely indisputable. Different taxes for different parts of the UK are a good thing. It will encourage innovation, force government to behave more responsibly and make the system more flexible. The taxes themselves might be bad – but the competition will be great.
The SNP has been arguing for years that the rich should pay higher taxes to support more generous public services. Now it has a chance to put that theory into practice. From this week, anyone earning more than £150,000 a year will pay more in tax than in the rest of the UK. The performance of the Scottish economy is already dismal, and maybe higher taxes are a way to fix that, but you wouldn't want to bet your last bottle of single malt on it. And yet, while that might be true, a majority of Scottish voters clearly support centre-Left economics, and they are surely entitled to see if it works.
As are the Welsh. From this month, the country has its own unique taxes for the first time in eight centuries. A land transaction tax and landfill tax will make a significant difference, with the regional assembly predicting they could raise an extra £1bn in revenue. 
Likewise, if the original timetable had been stuck to, Northern Ireland would have had its own rate of corporation tax from this week – it would have been 12.5pc to match the Republic. That was postponed, but is still on track for 2020. 
We are heading towards a patchwork of different rates. And yet no one should be scared of that, even if it will cause a few headaches for accountants. In truth, different rates could be great – for three reasons.
First, it will encourage innovation. Maybe the Welsh way of taxing land will turn out to be better than the system of stamp duties – and given the way chancellors now change the rates about as often as their socks it could hardly be much worse. Perhaps Scotland will discover that a 46pc top rate raises revenue painlessly? Maybe Northern Ireland will find that lower corporation tax turns Londonderry into a tech hub? We will find out in the next few years. The more new ideas are tried, the better. If they work, the rest of the country can copy them. If not, at least we learnt something. 
Next, it will make the assemblies and parliaments more responsible. There is nothing easier in the world than spending other people’s money. As power has been devolved, the different countries within the UK have taken far more control of their own affairs. If they want to spend money, then they should be raising it as well. That way, they will have to explain to their voters what taxes they are increasing, and how they are planning to spend the cash.

Finally, it will be more flexible. The UK has an incredibly varied economy, from hyper-rich London, to middle-income manufacturing regions, to relatively poor ones. It may well be impossible to design a single tax system that suits all of them. In London, you could make a case for higher property taxes; in Lancaster, less so. Over time, tax rates could be tailored to local economies.

Lots of countries have flexible rates. Switzerland has tax competition between its cantons, and the US between different states. It may well have resulted in lower taxes overall. The taxes the Scots or the Welsh introduce might be good or bad. But the competition between the four UK nations can only be an improvement.