Now is the time to change our economic model
The budget may not reverse our shrinking workforce but higher wages could just be the spur firms need to innovate
It was billed as the “back to work” budget. Jeremy Hunt promised to solve one of the most pressing problems holding back growth: “labour supply”.
There is a good reason why Hunt is worried about Britain’s shortage of workers. Wages are on the rise as employers struggle to fill a million vacancies. All else equal, wage rises exacerbate inflation, prompting consumers to bid up the cost of everything, which in turn raises pressure to increase wages. What results is the dreaded wage-price spiral, last seen in the 1970s.
So the government is right to worry about inflation, which erodes living standards and savings. But is it right to think the solution is to expand the workforce to strangle wage growth? I’m not so sure.
The conventional view is that rising wages caused by labour shortages are a very bad thing. Workers are one of the main costs employers face (the others being capital and raw materials). If these costs go up, the argument goes, innovation is harder and productivity suffers.
Economists point to the 1970s and successful modern economies to argue that keeping a lid on wage rises — as Germany or China have done encourages investment so wages can rise sustainably. “Good” wage rises, they’ll tell you, come only after you’ve put in the hard work of efficiency improvements.
If this model is universally true, it’s bad news for the world, not just the UK. Across the OECD, the share of the population that is working age has been falling since 2011. These market economies are also having fewer and fewer babies, so this trend will accelerate. High levels of immigration have not offset either trend despite generating political backlashes that make more immigration a hard sell.
The UK has an additional problem not seen in most other countries: a cohort who simply stopped working during Covid and haven’t come back. Hunt unveiled a plethora of measures designed to lure these people back into the workforce: removing the pension savings cap, changing the disability system so the disabled do not lose benefits if they work, toughening benefit requirements for the non-disabled and offering free childcare for babies (from next year). These measures will address “the two biggest barriers that stop business growing: investment incentives and labour supply”, he said.
In truth, although these measures may help to slow the workforce shrinkage, they will not reverse a trend decades in the making. In financial circles, it is easy to find pessimists who believe wage inflation is the new norm and that taxes on the working-age population will inexorably rise to meet the growing needs of the elderly.
What if this analysis has it all backwards, though? Wage inflation, rather than being a harbinger of decline, could just as easily be the incentive businesses finally need to invest in labour-saving technology. For years, our economy has been saddled with a long tail of firms that have failed to adopt basic productivity improvements, from new housebuilding techniques to bookkeeping software or automated seed-sowing devices. Many of these improvements do not require huge outlays or unimaginable new advances in technology. So why haven’t they happened? The likeliest explanation is surely that, with wages stagnant and the demographic cliff-edge yet to hit, companies simply have not bothered to upgrade their equipment or lay on training to improve workforce productivity.
Now, after a decade of ignoring the inevitable workforce crunch, employers have a pressing need they cannot fill in the usual way. This is a very different backdrop to the wage inflation of the 1970s, which forms the basis of the modern economist’s dread of high pay. Back then, the industries leading the charge to put up salaries were state-run and beholden to overwhelming union power. The working-age population was growing strongly and Britain was saddled with a whole backlog of useless capital stock, which had not been written down to its proper value. It could not have been innovated into profitability, even if the government had been the right vehicle to do it.
The situation now is different. The workforce is shrinking and will continue to do so even if the budget has its intended effect. This is happening in rival economies too. And the demand for new technology and workers who can deploy it is high, whether it’s heat pump installers, administrators or engineers.
What’s more, until the last year or so, the fear haunting many Davos panels and business-school essays was that automation would lead to mass unemployment. The solicitous intellectuals fretted: what were all those laid-off workers going to do?
Now, automation looks like the solution to our woes and high wages the trigger to spur investment in it. Those jobs that cannot be automated, such as social care, can soak up the workers whose jobs have been replaced by more efficient technology. There may be a mismatch between the skills required in our economy and the skills available, but that is not the same thing as a high wage problem. It is an education problem rather than a labour shortage.
Instead of asking how we bring wages down and fill the worker shortage, we should ask how we unleash the economy to fix this problem. If energy costs, poor access to training, shoddy infrastructure and planning regulations get in the way, the process of innovation could easily get stuck, replicating the barriers to progress that fed the 1970s wage-price inflation spiral. But that is not an inevitable.
In the mid 18th century, English and French glassmakers engaged in a competitive fight for market dominance. Delaunay Deslandes, the director of a French firm, thought his position secure because the English “could never make [glass] that would enter into competition with ours for the price. Our Frenchmen eat soup with a little butter and vegetables . . . Your Englishmen eat meat and a great deal of it and they drink beer continually.” English labour, in short, was just too expensive.
Deslandes was wrong. England’s high labour costs and cheap energy (coal) created the perfect incentive structure for innovation. Within a decade or so, English glassmaking was operating at a sixth of the cost of the French, despite paying workers more. What seemed to be our Achilles heel instead formed part of the formula for success. There is no reason why it should not be the case again today. If this government is serious about changing Britain’s economic model, now is its chance.
Governments Can't Blame Inflation on Energy and Putin Anymore
TAGS Money and Banks
At the end of February 2023, the price of oil (WTI and Brent), Henry Hub and ICE natural gas, aluminum, copper, steel, corn, wheat, and the Baltic Dry Index are below the February 2022 levels.
The Supply Chain Index and the global supply-demand balance, published by Morgan Stanley, have declined to September 2022 levels. However, the latest inflation readings are hugely concerning.
Considering the previously mentioned prices of commodities and freight, if price inflation were a “cost-push” phenomenon, it would have collapsed to 2 percent levels already. However, both headline and core inflation measures, from the Consumer Price Index (CPI) to Personal Consumer Expenditure Prices (PCE) show extremely elevated levels and rising core inflationary pressures.
We have mentioned numerous times that there is no such thing as “cost-push” price inflation. It is only more units of currency going toward relatively scarce goods and services.
The monetary aspect of inflation has been proven on the way up and in the commodity correction. The Federal Reserve’s rate hikes have deflated the price of commodities despite rising geopolitical tensions, supply challenges, and robust demand growth. Rate hikes make it more expensive to store, take long positions, and finance margin calls. Powell offset the entire supply-demand tightness impact on prices.
Governments cannot blame price inflation on Putin’s war or the so-called “supply chain disruptions” anymore. Printing money above demand is the only thing that makes prices rise in unison. If a price rises due to an exogenous reason but the quantity of currency remains equal, all other prices do not rise. A PCE index of 4.5 percent in January 2023 with all the main commodities below the January 2022 level shows how high inflationary pressures are.
Price inflation is accumulated, and the narrative is trying to convince us that bringing down inflation from 8 percent to 5 percent in 2024 will be a success. No. It will be a massive destruction of more than 20 percent of purchasing power of citizens from inflation in the period.
However, rate hikes are not enough. Broad-based money growth needs to come down rapidly. So far, in the United States, broad money growth is flat and has declined to more reasonable levels in December 2022. However, the latest European Central Bank reading of broad money growth in the euro area points to a 4.1 percent increase, which is very high compared to modest gross domestic product (GDP) growth and certainly very high compared with the estimates for 2023.
Broad money growth was too aggressive in 2022 and it may take some time to ease the inflationary pressures to a level that does not make citizens even poorer.
Two recent papers published by the Bank of International Settlements remind us that money growth was the main culprit for the price inflation surge. Claudio Borio, Boris Hoffmann, and Egon Zakrajšek conclude that
(Does money growth help explain the recent inflation surge?). Reis explains that “Inflation rose because central banks allowed it to rise. Rather than highlighting isolated mistakes in judgment, this paper points instead to underlying forces that created a tolerance for inflation that persisted even after the deviation from target became large” (The burst of high inflation in 2021–22: how and why did we get here?)
The supply chain and Ukraine war excuse has vanished, but inflation remains too high. Many market participants want rate cuts and money supply growth to see higher markets, with multiple and valuation expansion. However, rate cuts are very unlikely in this scenario and central banks know they have caused a problem that will take more time than expected to correct.
Governments cannot expect price inflation to correct when public spending is rising, which means higher consumption of new monetary units via deficit and debt.
Citizens are suffering these inflationary pressures via weakening real wage growth added to much higher cost of living as the prices of nonreplaceable goods and services—education, healthcare, rents, and essential purchases—are rising much faster than the headline CPI suggests.
We are all poorer, even if headline price inflation is slightly lower. Slowing inflation growth does not mean lower prices, just a slower pace of destruction of the purchasing power of currencies.
Someone will invent another excuse to blame price inflation on anything except the only thing that causes prices to rise at the same time: printing currency well above demand.
Daniel Lacalle