Relatively simple dissection of the reasons behind the very low interest rates the UK government has to pay at present. Follow the links to check out other things you should be aware of:
http://www.tutor2u.net/blog/index.php/economics/comments/astonishingly-low-interest-rates-on-uk-government-debt-cause-and-effects
Quote of the day
“I find economics increasingly satisfactory, and I think I am rather good at it.”– John Maynard Keynes
Saturday, 31 January 2015
Friday, 30 January 2015
Wednesday, 28 January 2015
R&D spending by country courtesy of Thomson Reuters:
Just a thought: During the Cold War R&D spending in the US was 5% of GDP. During that time we had many, many technological advances. What will it take to get the state to pay for serious scientific research that leads to "proper" advancement of our knowledge (and secures our future)?
graphic of the day
graphic of the day
Labels:
budget,
capital spending,
global economy,
government spending,
investment,
R&D,
supply-side
Tuesday, 27 January 2015
The impact of a $ bull market - John Mauldin
As promised, a link to the article that covered the impact of a $ bull market in depth - before anyone really noticed the rising $. This change is an undercurrent of huge significance for the global economy; it will unfold as we approach the exam. If some of the content is inaccessible, ask me. Most of it is very clear and accessible.
A Scary Story for Emerging Markets
A Scary Story for Emerging Markets
Labels:
$,
bail-out,
BoP,
borrowing,
crisis,
currency,
debt,
exchange rates,
global economy,
globalisation,
growth,
international competition
Short video on the UK banking system - essential exam info
Monday, 26 January 2015
Resources for Exchange Rates
Exchange Rates
Follow-on material for the lessons on exchange rates:
Tutor2u theory notes
http://www.tutor2u.net/economics/revision-notes/a2-macro-exchange-rate.html
mjmfoodie video
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=xwtgByffoUw
EOL theory notes
http://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Global_economics/Exchange_rates.html
For applied examples please peruse the IB International Economics Scoop It board.
http://www.scoop.it/t/ib-international-economics
Tutor2u theory notes
http://www.tutor2u.net/economics/revision-notes/a2-macro-exchange-rate.html
mjmfoodie video
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=xwtgByffoUw
EOL theory notes
http://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Global_economics/Exchange_rates.html
For applied examples please peruse the IB International Economics Scoop It board.
http://www.scoop.it/t/ib-international-economics
Great Economist article on internal labour mobility
Internal migration
Not on your bike
Britons are moving around less than they used to
“RIFF-RAFF”, Ken Loach’s 1991 film about poverty in Margaret Thatcher’s Britain, starts on a building site in London. A Cockney foreman bosses around a motley group of migrant workers, mocking their backgrounds and their abilities. Later the workers retire to a squat to drink cans of lager. Today the film resembles a period piece—not because foremen are more decent, necessarily, but because the migrant labourers in “Riff-Raff” are British.
Moving south for work in hard times was a defining feature of life in 20th-century Britain. Yet though London’s economy continues to outperform the north’s, the flow has slowed. Research by Anthony Champion of Newcastle University shows that 49% of unskilled workers changed address between 1971 and 1981. Just 36% did between 2001 and 2011. Overall net migration to the south of England from the rest of Britain has barely increased since 2007 (see chart). Most of that rise was driven not by more northerners moving south but by fewer southerners moving north. British society, long among the most dynamic in Europe, appears to be settling down.
Several things explain this. In the 1980s people fled cities such as Liverpool because their industries were dying. They eventually expired, while the financial crash of the early 1990s reduced London’s appeal. Today most of Britain’s big cities have mixed economies, so fewer people need to move to find jobs. Americans are also moving less often (though still more than Britons) as the country’s metropolises become more similar.
Though home-ownership rates in Britain have been falling lately, a much larger proportion of the population owns now than in the 1970s and 1980s. That freezes people in place, because buying and selling a house is far costlier and more time-consuming than moving from one rented place to another. Moving across the country was easier in the days when mothers were more likely to be housewives. Finally, wider car ownership and better public transport make commuting easier: the biggest drop has been in short moves.
But the most pronounced change seems to be cultural. People used to move mostly for work. They now move routinely, but for other reasons. Each year teenagers travel for university, accounting for much of the inflow into cities such as Manchester and Nottingham. In 2012 fully 23% of 19-year-olds moved local authority, against around 4% of the whole population. A similar flow of 21-year-olds goes to London, which sucks in about a third of new graduates. From there, almost every borough has a net outflow of people to the rest of the south of England, as people move out to commuter towns (London’s population grows anyway because of births and foreign immigration).
This churn is most powerful in the south-east. In 2012, 3.1% of London’s population moved to other parts of Britain, while 2.5% moved in. Cambridge, Canterbury, Norwich and Oxford were similarly mobile. But in the north-west of England movement was about half as common as in London. The places with the fewest migrants, both in and out, are struggling industrial towns like Barrow-in-Furness, Hartlepool and Sunderland.
The main driver of changes in migration in this model is the housing market, not the labour market. Flows into university towns and then south are largely constant. But flows out of London depend on how many people are buying or selling homes. In the mid-2000s migration out of the capital and northwards jumped as people sold up and moved. From the financial crisis until recently, however, Londoners have struggled to get mortgages, leaving many stuck in the capital.
Does this matter? The mass migration of the young is not always popular. Jamie Reed, the MP for Copeland, a district in Cumbria, gripes that the best graduates from his constituency rarely move back after finishing university. Yet lack of movement is probably even worse. Alan Manning, an academic at the London School of Economics, suggests low migration makes struggling towns more vulnerable to economic shocks: if they cannot move to work, people who lose their jobs will take much longer to find new ones. Places such as Merthyr Tydfil, a Welsh former steel town, might be better off if people found it easier to up sticks.
As the housing market begins to move again, migration is likely to pick up. In the longer run, falling home-ownership may reduce the barriers to moving. Yet the new pattern is likely to stick. That will increase the importance of universities to cities’ economies: without them, attracting skilled workers will be difficult. It also suggests that international migration will continue to fill the gaps in the south’s booming low-skilled service sector. But perhaps that is no bad thing. Being forced to move by recession was hardly pleasant. In the new model, people spread about the country at their leisure.
Short FT videos on employment issues
Saturday, 17 January 2015
A few articles - Swiss franc, balancing the UK budget, ditching inflation targets
Swiss franc is a sideshow, it's the euro that matters
Will politicians really balance the budget?
This is a really interesting read for A2 students wanting solid extension material for the inflation/deflation debate; it argues that rather than a flat 2% target, regardless of economic conditions, an "average" rate (a bit like the balance of payments) should be the target. Higher inflation that does not stem from damaging excess demand should be tolerated, as should deflation from benign sources. If you do get an inflation/deflation question in the exam there is material here to extend your answer and garner marks:
BoE should drop its inflation target
Will politicians really balance the budget?
This is a really interesting read for A2 students wanting solid extension material for the inflation/deflation debate; it argues that rather than a flat 2% target, regardless of economic conditions, an "average" rate (a bit like the balance of payments) should be the target. Higher inflation that does not stem from damaging excess demand should be tolerated, as should deflation from benign sources. If you do get an inflation/deflation question in the exam there is material here to extend your answer and garner marks:
BoE should drop its inflation target
Labels:
BoE,
budget,
capital spending,
currency,
debt,
deficit,
deflation,
ECB,
euro,
fiscal,
forex,
GDP,
inflation,
investment,
nominal,
productivity,
QE,
structural
Solving Europe's youth unemployment
As we have learned, youth unemployment across Europe is very high, with the highest levels in Spain, Greece and Italy. What can be done to resolve this? This short article looks at what might be done, which gives you material for essays, as well as highlighting issues that could hinder these solutions (evaluation!). I am particularly intrigued by the suggestion in the final paragraph; is it a practical example, where the overall cost (and waste) is worth the potential outcome? Or is it an example of a desperate attempt to circumvent the structural issues European politicans are reluctant to tackle?
http://www.tutor2u.net/blog/index.php/economics/comments/can-adam-smith-solve-the-problem-of-youth-unemployment-in-europe
http://www.tutor2u.net/blog/index.php/economics/comments/can-adam-smith-solve-the-problem-of-youth-unemployment-in-europe
Friday, 16 January 2015
Another interesting news day for fiscal policy/supply-side topic
On Radio 4 this am a commentator interviewed to talk about the Chancellor's fiscal rules proposals, while broadly agreeing the new rules are good, made the comment that "with the crumbling state of our infrastructure, and with the government's ability to borrow at 0% in real terms over 50 years, [can it?] I wish they would borrow to invest in the future."
Some time later there was a news item describing how the Public Accounts Committee [what's that?] chaired by Margaret Hodge had questioned the value for money of the whole HS2 project, pointing out that the estimated cost of the the first stage had already risen from £17bn to £21bn over the last few months.
In addition I note a headline in the Daily Telegraph:
Some time later there was a news item describing how the Public Accounts Committee [what's that?] chaired by Margaret Hodge had questioned the value for money of the whole HS2 project, pointing out that the estimated cost of the the first stage had already risen from £17bn to £21bn over the last few months.
In addition I note a headline in the Daily Telegraph:
Whitehall's quickfire £1bn spree to spend surplus in foreign aid budget
"MPs say the fact that taxpayer funds were spent so quickly raised serious questions about whether value for money was achieved..."
Anyone who wants to achieve a B or higher should be all over this sort of material; it is the second most effective way of showing appropriate knowledge to the examiner. What is the first?
Anyone who wants to achieve a B or higher should be all over this sort of material; it is the second most effective way of showing appropriate knowledge to the examiner. What is the first?
Labels:
borrowing,
budget deficit,
government spending,
waste
Thursday, 15 January 2015
The BBC on the current inflation conditions
A typically accessible piece by the BBC; AS students should read this for an understanding of our current topic in the current context. A2 students could do worse than use this for context and revision.
Why apologise for low inflation?
Why apologise for low inflation?
Emily has sent an article on deflation:
Apart from the fact this is a very good example of keeping up to date with a critical development in macroeconomics, it also raises an important question. My response is below:
http://news.sky.com/story/1407096/why-record-inflation-fall-is-not-all-good-news
Hopefully, following several lessons on the subject, you are able to make a reasoned judgement of that? He has not really added much to the debate (this level of news article is good for current context, but for depth of analysis we must turn elsewhere. Broadly his points are accurate - price falls should be positive, up to a point, but at some point they can become dangerously negative. It is up to you to make that case eh?
Don't forget that we are in a globalised economy, where circumstances occurring elsewhere have a significant impact here; however, all economies are different - at different stages of development, at different stages of the cycle, and with different internal rigidities and structural dynamics. For example, if the problem with falling prices becomes one of falling wages, should the government intervene and set a wage floor to stop a wage-price spiral down? I speculate we might see such talk in Europe if deflation persists and spreads, and it may gain traction; over here I doubt it - we are different.
Thanks for showing me - us! - the article. I hope everyone else takes the time to read it I am putting this on the blog).
http://news.sky.com/story/1407096/why-record-inflation-fall-is-not-all-good-news
Hopefully, following several lessons on the subject, you are able to make a reasoned judgement of that? He has not really added much to the debate (this level of news article is good for current context, but for depth of analysis we must turn elsewhere. Broadly his points are accurate - price falls should be positive, up to a point, but at some point they can become dangerously negative. It is up to you to make that case eh?
Don't forget that we are in a globalised economy, where circumstances occurring elsewhere have a significant impact here; however, all economies are different - at different stages of development, at different stages of the cycle, and with different internal rigidities and structural dynamics. For example, if the problem with falling prices becomes one of falling wages, should the government intervene and set a wage floor to stop a wage-price spiral down? I speculate we might see such talk in Europe if deflation persists and spreads, and it may gain traction; over here I doubt it - we are different.
Thanks for showing me - us! - the article. I hope everyone else takes the time to read it I am putting this on the blog).
Joss Bolton
|
Economics Teacher
|
Lingfield Notre Dame School
|
From: Emily
Sent: 14 January 2015 22:00
Sent: 14 January 2015 22:00
Tuesday, 13 January 2015
Soc Gen note on 3 elections this year:
These are clipped from the document; if anyone DOES want to follow any of the links I will forward the document.
Sunday, 11 January 2015
Short series on oil prices
Useful snapshot of the world of oil prices, with good material for essays. The information comes in a series of short articles, and covers why price is falling, who wins & who loses etc. There may well be other useful links from this author:
http://marketrealist.com/2014/12/drop-in-oil-prices-economic-implications/?utm_source=yahoo&utm_medium=feed&utm_content=toc-1&utm_campaign=how-the-rising-dollar-is-causing-oil-prices-to-fall
http://marketrealist.com/2014/12/drop-in-oil-prices-economic-implications/?utm_source=yahoo&utm_medium=feed&utm_content=toc-1&utm_campaign=how-the-rising-dollar-is-causing-oil-prices-to-fall
Read the last 2 paragraphs
Well, Congress and the White House did indeed play the austerian card from mid-2011 onward. The federal budget deficit has declined from 8.4% of GDP in 2011 to a predicted 2.9% of GDP for all of 2014. And, according to the International Monetary Fund, the structural deficit (sometimes called the “full-employment deficit”), a measure of fiscal stimulus, has fallen from 7.8% of potential GDP to 4% of potential GDP from 2011 to 2014.
Krugman has vigorously protested that deficit reduction has prolonged and even intensified what he repeatedly calls a “depression” (or sometimes a “low-grade depression”). Only fools like the United Kingdom’s leaders (who reminded him of the Three Stooges) could believe otherwise.
Yet, rather than a new recession, or an ongoing depression, the US unemployment rate has fallen from 8.6% in November 2011 to 5.8% in November 2014. Real economic growth in 2011 stood at 1.6%, and the IMF expects it to be 2.2% for 2014 as a whole. GDP in the third quarter of 2014 grew at a vigorous 5% annual rate, suggesting that aggregate growth for all of 2015 will be above 3%.
So much for Krugman’s predictions. Not one of his New York Times commentaries in the first half of 2013, when “austerian” deficit cutting was taking effect, forecast a major reduction in unemployment or that economic growth would recover to brisk rates. On the contrary, “the disastrous turn toward austerity has destroyed millions of jobs and ruined many lives,” he argued, with the US Congress exposing Americans to “the imminent threat of severe economic damage from short-term spending cuts.” As a result, “Full recovery still looks a very long way off,” he warned. “And I’m beginning to worry that it may never happen.”
I raise all of this because Krugman took a victory lap in his end-of-2014 column on “The Obama Recovery.” The recovery, according to Krugman, has come not despite the austerity he railed against for years, but because we “seem to have stopped tightening the screws: Public spending isn’t surging, but at least it has stopped falling. And the economy is doing much better as a result.”
That is an incredible claim. The budget deficit has been brought down sharply, and unemployment has declined. Yet Krugman now says that everything has turned out just as he predicted.
In fact, Krugman has been conflating two distinct ideas as if both were components of “progressive” thinking. On one hand, he has been the “conscience of a liberal,” rightly focusing on how government can combat poverty, poor health, environmental degradation, rising inequality, and other social ills. I admire that side of Krugman’s writing, and, as I wrote in my book The Price of Civilization, I agree with him.
On the other hand, Krugman has inexplicably taken up the mantle of crude aggregate-demand management, making it seem that favoring large budget deficits in recent years is also part of progressive economics. (Krugman’s position is sometimes called Keynesianism, but John Maynard Keynes knew much better than Krugman that we should not depend on mechanistic “demand multipliers” to set the unemployment rate.) Deficits were not increased enough in 2009 to escape from high unemployment, he insisted, and were falling dangerously fast after 2010.
Obviously, recent trends – a significant decline in the unemployment rate and a reasonably high and accelerating rate of economic growth – cast doubt on Krugman’s macroeconomic diagnosis (though not on his progressive politics). And the same trends have been apparent in the United Kingdom, where Prime Minister David Cameron’s government has cut the structural budget deficit from 8.4% of potential GDP in 2010 to 4.1% in 2014, while the unemployment rate has fallen from 7.9% when Cameron took office to 6%, according to the most recent data for the fall of 2014.
To be clear, I believe that we do need more government spending as a share of GDP – for education, infrastructure, low-carbon energy, research and development, and family benefits for low-income families. But we should pay for this through higher taxes on high incomes and high net worth, a carbon tax, and future tolls collected on new infrastructure. We need the liberal conscience, but without the chronic budget deficits.
There is nothing progressive about large budget deficits and a rising debt-to-GDP ratio. After all, large deficits have no reliable effect on reducing unemployment, and deficit reduction can be consistent with falling unemployment.
Krugman is a great economic theorist – and a great polemicist. But he should replace his polemical hat with his analytical one and reflect more deeply on recent experience: deficit-cutting accompanied by recovery, job creation, and lower unemployment. This should be an occasion for him to rethink his long-standing macroeconomic mantra, rather than claiming vindication for ideas that recent trends seem to contradict.
Read more at http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/krugman-budget-deficit-support-by-jeffrey-d-sachs-2015-01#BxTfZbi1ZHf3e50v.99
Labels:
austerity,
budget deficit,
debt,
deficit,
government spending,
IMF,
Keynes,
Krugman
Is George Osborne really a Keynesian?
A question worth asking, as he has singularly failed to achieve his budgetary goals. This is a very interesting article by an arch-Keynesian, Lord Skidelsky, and he asks some very important questions about policy for the next government:
http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/osborne-deficit-growth-by-robert-skidelsky-2014-12
http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/osborne-deficit-growth-by-robert-skidelsky-2014-12
UK tax revenues:
A lot of the article is too specific to be of value to you, but there is a very nice graphic near the end detailing sources of tax revenue (not sure if NICs are included in income tax). There is also some information on moves to harmonise taxes across the EU:
This comes at the time France drops its 75% top rate:
When fiscal become supply-side
Sunday Times
Tim Shipman and Danny Fortson Published: 11 January 2015
- Comment (21)
The oil price collapse has led to a sharp drop in North Sea drilling and a flurry of job and pay cuts (Getty)
GEORGE OSBORNE is working on an emergency tax cut to reverse an alarming decline in investment that threatens the future of the North Sea.
The chancellor told The Sunday Times that “more action” was needed to help the industry after the oil price plunged to $49 a barrel — a 57% dive in just six months.
The collapse has led to a sharp drop in North Sea drilling and a flurry of job and pay cuts. The industry employs 375,000 people and is one of the biggest contributors to the exchequer.
Executives want action to prevent a full-blown crisis. The chancellor said he may use the budget in March to unveil a tax bailout.
“In December, I announced some cuts in our oil taxes and set out the plan for the future,” he said. “I don’t want to pre-empt the budget but I can see that may well involve further reducing the burden of tax on investment in the North Sea.”
Production last year averaged just 1.2m barrels a day — a 75% drop from the 1999 high. Companies say one of the biggest challenges is the tax take, which can run to 80% for old fields. The basic levy is 60%.
A supplementary corporation tax charge was introduced in 2002 by Gordon Brown. Osborne lopped 2% from the basic rate in the autumn statement but the industry says this is not enough.
The proposals under discussion include removing the supplementary tax altogether for new developments, and creating a simpler regime to replace the jumble of allowances and tax breaks that govern North Sea work.
The drilling of exploration wells last year fell to levels not seen since the industry was in its infancy. The French giant Total cancelled a project last week. Several comp–anies, including BP and Wood Group, have cut contractors’ pay.
Osborne said: “We have a record amount of investment in the North Sea. A lot of these investments take a long-term view but there’s no doubt the dramatic fall in the oil price has raised questions about future investment in the North Sea.”
What do people on benefits actually get:
Goodwill to all men: why we should be astonished by the UK welfare state
Having read a good amount recently on food banks in the UK this week, I had a little wander around the benefits system. I looked at a postcode in the southeast of England to see just how much you get from the welfare state in the UK if you aren’t working at all.
I started with a couple with two children and added up their housing benefit, jobseeker’s allowance, tax credits and child benefit. The result? A tax-free income of £24,269. That’s the equivalent of an earned (and hence taxable) income of £32,000. That’s very significantly more than the number we are always given as the UK’s average wage.
Then I looked at a single mother with two kids. Her payments come out to just under £24,000, so again an earned income equivalent of just under £32,000.
Finally, I looked at a single unemployed man of working age. His benefit payments in the same area come to a tax-free total of £12,300 with £7,600 of that being housing benefit. I then looked up the accommodation available to rent at that price or less in the area. Rightmove provided 68 pages of possibilities.
Now, none of these amounts add up to fortunes. But they don’t add up to anything approaching absolute poverty either. Live frugally and stay out of debt, and things should be fine. Not exactly luxurious, but fine.
So what of the food banks, you will say? “They prove we don’t pay enough in benefits.” But they don’t really prove anything of the sort.
They prove that sometimes the state messes up benefit payments and leaves nasty delays. They prove that people aren’t good at managing money. They suggest that not everyone puts rent and food before fags and booze (but we don’t want to get into a discussion about the deserving and the undeserving here). They confirm that supply creates its own demand.
They might prove that some landlords are unscrupulous or that some families have more financial emergencies than others. They might confirm that we have a problem with mental illness in the UK. And they certainly prove that debt is a major problem in the UK: once you are in debt at high interest rates very few incomes are ever high enough – and £24,000 really isn’t. See my column from yesterday on this matter of debt here.
But are any of these things really a good argument for paying more in welfare? We’ve heard a lot about the misery of “the cuts” and the horrors of food banks recently. But wouldn’t it be nice if just sometimes commentators focused not on the occasional failures of our welfare machine, but on how astonishing it is to live in a country where the taxpayer via the state is prepared to pay up for what is a effectively a guaranteed minimum income for every person in the country (just over £12k a head, it seems) alongside state funded education and healthcare, with very little asked in return?
Because in an age when we are all said to be individualistic and endlessly selfish, it seems to me that on the goodwill to all men front, it really is quite something.
Thursday, 8 January 2015
Important - free resource from Surrey Library:
Mrs Yeoman has investigated a resource that is free for you to use FROM HOME (i.e. the school would be charged for this resource, you as Surrey residents can access it at no charge). The link for this is:
http://new.surreycc.gov.uk/people-and-community/libraries/libraries-for-learning-and-research/adult-online-reference-shelf
Mrs Yeoman is enrolling the senior students class by class, starting with Year 13, so you have avoided the hard work, which I know you will be pleased about.
When you access this resource can you please let me know what is available specifically for Economics & Business.
http://new.surreycc.gov.uk/people-and-community/libraries/libraries-for-learning-and-research/adult-online-reference-shelf
Mrs Yeoman is enrolling the senior students class by class, starting with Year 13, so you have avoided the hard work, which I know you will be pleased about.
When you access this resource can you please let me know what is available specifically for Economics & Business.
Wednesday, 7 January 2015
Understanding the oil situation
Very politically informative piece from the Spectator:
http://blogs.spectator.co.uk/coffeehouse/2015/01/the-saudis-oily-game-is-an-ambitious-one-heres-how-to-understand-it/
http://blogs.spectator.co.uk/coffeehouse/2015/01/the-saudis-oily-game-is-an-ambitious-one-heres-how-to-understand-it/
This time last year...
some commentators were predicting deflation; from a different source, perhaps, but uneerily accurate - worth reading to compare then with now.
http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/comment/ambroseevans_pritchard/10605957/World-risks-deflationary-shock-as-BRICS-puncture-credit-bubbles.html
http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/comment/ambroseevans_pritchard/10605957/World-risks-deflationary-shock-as-BRICS-puncture-credit-bubbles.html
Tuesday, 6 January 2015
Sunday, 4 January 2015
Do we have a date for a QE announcement from the ECB?
Despite stiff opposition from the German camp, many commentators believe an announcement is imminent; certainly this economist, writing on www.project-syndicate.org thinks so:
http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/ecb-bond-purchases-by-jean-pisani-ferry-2014-12
Where will all the workers go? - technology vs workers:
"The rapid development of smart software over the last few decades has been perhaps the most important force shaping the coming manufacturing revolution. Software innovation, together with 3D printing technologies, will open the door to those workers who are educated enough to participate; for everyone else, however, it may feel as though the revolution is happening elsewhere. Indeed, the factory of the future may be 1,000 robots and one worker manning them. Even the shop floor can be swept better and cheaper by a Roomba robot than by any worker." Read on...
This ties in with this infographic from the Daily Telegraph:
Nouriel Roubini in Project Syndicate on employment in the future
This ties in with this infographic from the Daily Telegraph:
Technology & jobs
Saturday, 3 January 2015
Project Syndicate on why growth has been slow
Michael Spence
Five Reasons for Slow Growth 29 Dec 2014
Read more at http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/slow-economic-growth-reasons-by-michael-spence-2014-12#oKozbavS1O2Im8fJ.99
Five Reasons for Slow Growth 29 Dec 2014
MILAN – A remarkable pattern has emerged since the 2008 global financial crisis: Governments, central banks, and international financial institutions have consistently had to revise their growth forecasts downward. With very few exceptions, this has been true of projections for the global economy and individual countries alike.
It is a pattern that has caused real damage, because overoptimistic forecasts delay measures that are needed to boost growth, and thus impede full economic recovery. Forecasters need to come to terms with what has gone wrong; fortunately, as the post-crisis experience lengthens, some of the missing pieces are coming into clear focus. I have identified five.
First, the capacity for fiscal intervention – at least among developed economies – has been underutilized. As former United States Deputy Secretary of the Treasury Frank Newman argued in a recent book, Freedom from National Debt, a country’s capacity for fiscal intervention is better assessed by examining its aggregate balance sheet than by the traditional method of comparing its debt (a liability) to its GDP (a flow).
Reliance on the traditional method has resulted in missed opportunities, particularly given that productive public-sector investment can more than pay for itself. Investments in infrastructure, education, and technology help drive long-term growth. They increase competitiveness, facilitate innovation, and boost private-sector returns, generating growth and employment. It does not take a lot of growth to offset even substantial investment – especially given current low borrowing costs.
Research by the International Monetary Fund has indicated that these fiscal multipliers – the second factor overlooked by forecasters – vary with underlying economic conditions. In economies with excess capacity (including human capital) and a high degree of structural flexibility, the multipliers are greater than once thought.
In the US, for instance, structural flexibility contributed to economic recovery and helped the country adapt to long-term technological changes and global market forces. In Europe, by contrast, structural change faces resistance. Fiscal stimulus in Europe may still be justified, but structural rigidity will lower its impact on long-term growth. Europe’s fiscal interventions would be easier to justify if they were accompanied by microeconomic reforms targeted at increasing flexibility.
A third piece of the forecast puzzle is the disparity between the behavior of financial markets and that of the real economy. Judged only by asset prices, one would have to conclude that growth is booming. Obviously, it is not.
A major contributor to this divergence has been ultra-loose monetary policy, which, by flooding financial markets with liquidity, was supposed to boost growth. But it remains unclear whether elevated asset prices are supporting aggregate demand or mainly shifting the distribution of wealth. It is equally unclear what will happen to asset prices when monetary assistance is withdrawn.
A fourth factor is the quality of government. In recent years, there has been no shortage of examples of governments abusing their powers to favor the ruling elite, their supporters, and a variety of special interests, with detrimental effects on regulation, public investment, the delivery of services, and growth. It is critically important that public services, public investment, and public policy are well managed. Countries that attract and motivate skilled public managers outperform their peers.
Finally, and most important, the magnitude and duration of the drop in aggregate demand has been greater than expected, partly because employment and median incomes have been lagging behind growth. This phenomenon preceded the crisis, and high levels of household debt have exacerbated its impact in the aftermath. The stagnation of incomes in the bottom 75% of the distribution presents an especially large challenge, because it depresses consumption, undermines social cohesion (and thus political stability and effectiveness), and decreases intergenerational mobility – especially where public education is poor.
Sometimes change occurs at a pace that outstrips the capacity of individuals and systems to respond. This appears to be one of those times. Labor markets have been knocked out of equilibrium as new technology and shifting global supply chains have caused demand in the labor market to change faster than supply can adjust.
This is not a permanent condition, but the transition will be long and complex. The same forces that are dramatically increasing the world economy’s productive potential are largely responsible for the adverse trends in income distribution. Digital technology and capital have eliminated middle-income jobs or moved them offshore, generating an excess supply of labor that has contributed to income stagnation precisely in that range.
A more muscular response will require an awareness of the nature of the challenge and a willingness to meet it by investing heavily in key areas – particularly education, health care, and infrastructure. It must be recognized that this is a difficult moment and countries must mobilize their resources to help their people with the transition.
That will mean redistributing income and ensuring access to essential basic services. If countering inequality and promoting intergenerational opportunity introduces some marginal inefficiencies and blunts some incentives, it is more than worth the price. Public provision of critical basic services like education or health care may never be as efficient as private-sector alternatives; but where efficiency entails exclusion and inequality of opportunity, public provision is not a mistake.
One hopes that a growing awareness of the significance of these and other factors will have a positive effect on policy agendas in the coming year.
Read more at http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/slow-economic-growth-reasons-by-michael-spence-2014-12#oKozbavS1O2Im8fJ.99
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)